Production, Manufacturing and Logistics
Coordination in decentralized assembly systems with uncertain component yields

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2005.09.036Get rights and content

Abstract

The literature on assembly systems with random component yields has focused on centralized systems, where a single decision maker chooses all components’ production quantities and incurs all the costs. We consider a decentralized setting where the component suppliers choose their production quantities based solely on their own cost/reward structure, and the assembly firm makes ordering decisions based on its own cost/reward structure. When the suppliers control their inputs but the outputs exhibit random yields, coordination in such systems becomes quite complex. In such situations, incentive alignment control mechanisms are needed so that the suppliers will choose production quantities as in the centralized system case. One such mechanism is to penalize the supplier with the worse delivery performance. We analyze the conditions under which system coordination is achieved while respecting participation constraints. Further, we determine the optimal component ordering policy for the assembly firm and derive the optimal coordinating penalties.

Introduction

In many systems, overall performance is determined by the agent who produces or delivers the least amount. “Minimum effort” or “weakest link” scenarios in team performance are explored by Van Huyck et al., 1990, Knez and Camerer, 1994, Cachon and Camerer, 1996. In the domain of production management, the prime examples are assembly systems—the number of complete kits available depends on the component in shortest supply (e.g., Gerchak and Wang, 2004). When agents control the inputs or efforts of their own activities, but the outputs exhibit random yields, coordination in such assembly systems becomes quite complex.

To date, the literature on assembly systems with random component yields (Singh et al., 1990, Gerchak et al., 1994, Gurnani et al., 1996, Gurnani et al., 2000) has focused on centralized systems, where a single decision maker chooses all components’ production quantities and incurs all the costs. For example, Gerchak et al. (1994) considered such systems with a product whose demand is known or uncertain, perfect or imperfect assembly stage, and stochastically proportional yields. Due to the need for simultaneously selecting production quantities of inter-dependent components, that problem is quite difficult to solve except in some special circumstances. Conceptually, however, the setting is a natural extension of well-studied single-item random yield models (e.g., Anupindi and Akella, 1993, Bassok and Akella, 1991, Bollapragada and Morton, 1999, Henig and Gerchak, 1990, Yano and Lee, 1995).

There is an extensive literature concerning the choice of quality by suppliers, contracting over it, and inspection policy for the buyer (Reyniers and Tapiero, 1995, Baiman et al., 2000). These papers do not deal with assembly systems or with lot-sizing. Baiman et al., 2004, Baiman and Netessine, 2004 do deal with assembly systems, but consider product quality only and not lot-sizing. So while the literature focuses on quality choice and monitoring, we focus on lot-sizing for given yield distributions. We assume a single supplier for each component, and thus do not explore multiple-sourcing (as in Cachon and Zhang, 2004).

The basic scenario we envision here is as follows. An assembly firm receives an order for d units of some product that is assembled using two components in amounts scaled to be equal (later, in Section 5, we discuss the extension of the model to the case of n components with identical cost and yield structures). It has to then decide how many units to order from its components suppliers. There are many examples of products assembled using critical components—NASA estimated that in the Challenger, there were approximately 4686 critical parts, each one, potentially crucial to the success of the mission. Other examples include using critical components to assemble cars, VCRs, etc.

The production process of the component suppliers is assumed to be imperfect (as is the case, for example, in semiconductor and electronics industries), and hence, their yields are random. In the first part of the paper, we consider a centralized system and determine optimal production quantities for the components. The centralized system solution serves as a benchmark for the decentralized setting.

For the decentralized problem, we first consider a contract form (referred to as the Additional Penalty contract) whereby the supplier with the worse delivery performance pays an extra penalty (in addition to the regular shortage penalty) to the assembly firm. The component suppliers choose their production quantities based solely on their own cost/reward structure in order to maximize profits subject to a participation constraint. The assembly firm would place orders from the suppliers, which may differ from its customer’s order size, based on its own cost/reward structure. In this contract, we assume that since both components are required in equal quantity, the assembly firm orders equal number of units from both the suppliers. However, the firm may choose penalty costs that are different for each supplier. The situation here can be viewed as two strategic “nested games” with uncertainty. The first is a Stackelberg game where the leader (the assembly firm) selects an order size, and the followers (the component suppliers facing random production yields) respond by selecting their production quantities. But the multiple “followers” (component suppliers) make their choices simultaneously, and, since their costs are interrelated, they may be viewed as actually playing a Nash-game, which is “nested” within the Stackelberg game. Comparative statics for the equilibrium are provided.

We also consider a second contract form where the firm may order unequal order quantities from the two suppliers. In this contract, we consider the case when there are regular shortage penalty costs only, that is, the assembly firm does not charge an additional penalty to the worse supplier.1

Another issue we explore is the ordering policy of the assembly firm. Since the suppliers make allowances for their own yield randomness (and, in case of the extra penalty contract, even for the other supplier’s yield randomness), need the firm do so as well? Using the optimal reaction function of the suppliers, we determine the optimal component ordering decisions for the assembly firm.

In order to achieve channel coordination, we show that by using the Additional Penalty contract, the firm can suitably place (equal) orders from the suppliers and set the regular and additional shortage penalty prices such that participation constraint for both the suppliers will be binding and thus the firm could retain all of the above-reservation channel profits. The Additional Penalty contract also offers the advantage in that the assembly firm, by suitably choosing the penalty prices, can order exactly equal to its demand and let the suppliers make their allowances for yield uncertainty. In the second contract with unequal order quantities, again we show that the assembly firm is able to achieve coordination and retain all above-reservation profits by suitable selection of regular shortage penalties. In this case, since the firm has the flexibility to order different quantities from the suppliers, it turns out that additional penalty costs are not necessary as regular shortage penalties are sufficient to achieve coordination. Interestingly, we also observe that if the suppliers are symmetric (that is, the components are identical), again we can just use regular shortage penalties in order to achieve coordination, that is, additional penalties are not needed when the suppliers are symmetric.

The recently emerging literature within operations management stressing the importance of coordination and control mechanisms in decentralized supply chains (e.g., Cachon, 2003, Gavirneni, 2001) did not consider assembly systems (but see Gerchak and Wang, 2004), and, by and large, also did not consider the implications of random yields. When yields are random, a direct link between an agent’s (component supplier’s) actions and their results, and thus impacts on the chain, does not exist, as they are separated by a layer of uncertainty.

In the OM literature on decentralized systems, “coordination” has to do with economic aspects—appropriate incentive systems are sought so that agents will behave as if system is centralized (as thus economically efficient), and/or in a manner most profitable to the leader. In an assembly setting, on the other hand, coordination is a “physical” concept (equal component quantities delivered in unison) as well as an economic one (these equal quantities are to be the “right” ones). Thus we mean more by “coordination” than the non-assembly literature.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we discuss the model assumptions and formulate the expected profit function for the suppliers for the additional penalty contract, as well as the resulting participation constraints. In Section 3, we consider the firm’s ordering problem for given penalty parameters and determine the optimal ordering policy. In Section 4, we analyze the conditions required for channel coordination where the firm can use the penalty parameters as levers, and show that by using the additional penalty contract, the firm is able to retain all of the above-reservation channel profits. We also model the second contract with unequal order quantities and show that regular shortage penalties are sufficient to achieve channel coordination. In Section 5, we discuss the extension of the model to the case of n-symmetric suppliers. Finally in Section 6, we summarize the results and discuss extensions.

Section snippets

Model formulation: Decentralized system

A firm receives an order of fixed size d at a unit price s. The opportunity loss for each unfilled unit is π. That cost may correspond to satisfying unmet demand by other, expensive, means. Due to its particular specifications, the filling of an order requires previously unavailable custom-made components, which have no other use. Production lead-time constraints permit only one run of each component, produced simultaneously. The product consists of two components with unit production costs c1

Firm’s order size selection problem

An issue we wish to explore is whether/when should an assembly/kitting firm, facing a known demand of d units, indeed order exactly d units from its suppliers. After all, the suppliers make allowances for their own yield randomness (and, in case of the extra penalty contract, even for other supplier’s yield randomness), so need the firm do so as well? Note that we assume that the suppliers will not deliver more than what is ordered from them, even if the resulting yield is higher. This is a

Channel coordination and division of profits

We start with case of the centralized model. If the component production quantities are x1 and x2 respectively, then the expected profits for the centralized system (superscript c) arePc=sE(unitssold)-c1x1+c2x2+πE(shortage)=sE{min(α1x1,α2x2,d)}-[c1x1+c2x2+πE{[d-min(α1x1,α2x2)]+}].Since the minimum of concave functions is concave, the expected profit function (14) above can be shown to be jointly concave in (x1, x2). Details will be omitted.

The solution to the centralized problem determines the

Model extension: n symmetric suppliers

In this section, we discuss the extension of the model to the case of n components with identical yield distributions and costs. The random fraction of component i units, (i = 1,  , n), which turn out to be good is αi, where αi has the cdf G and density g. We start with the analysis of the Centralized system and then discuss the Decentralized solution.

Conclusions and future research

In this paper, we considered an assembly system where the supply of components is uncertain due to random yield losses in the suppliers’ production processes, and due to strategic considerations by suppliers who constitute independent business entities. First, we considered a centralized system and determined the production quantities that minimized total system costs. We then considered a decentralized setting where a supplier is penalized for the shortage of its own delivery as well as a

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank an anonymous referee for all comments and suggestions that have improved the quality of the paper.

References (26)

  • R. Anupindi et al.

    Diversification under supply uncertainty

    Management Science

    (1993)
  • K.J. Arrow et al.

    Studies in the Mathematical Theory of Inventory and Production

    (1958)
  • Baiman, S., Netessine, S., 2004. The incentive effect of multiple sourcing. Working paper, Wharton...
  • S. Baiman et al.

    Information, contracting and quality costs

    Management Science

    (2000)
  • Baiman, S., Netessine, S., Kunreuther, H., 2004. Procurement in supply chains when end-product exhibits weakest-link...
  • Y. Bassok et al.

    Ordering and production decisions with supply quality and demand uncertainty

    Management Science

    (1991)
  • S. Bollapragada et al.

    Myopic heuristics for the random yield problem

    Operations Research

    (1999)
  • G.P. Cachon

    Supply chain coordination with contracts

  • G.P. Cachon et al.

    Loss avoidance and forward induction in coordinated games

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1996)
  • Cachon, G.P., Zhang, F., 2004. Procuring fast delivery. Part I: Multi-sourcing and scorecard allocation of demand via...
  • E. Clarke

    Multipart pricing of public goods

    Public Choice

    (1971)
  • J.W. Friedman

    Game Theory with Applications to Economics

    (1986)
  • S. Gavirneni

    Benefits of cooperation in a production distribution environment

    European Journal of Operational Research

    (2001)
  • Cited by (159)

    • The implications of contract timing on a supply chain with random yield

      2021, International Journal of Production Economics
    View all citing articles on Scopus

    Haresh Gurnani’s research was partially supported by a grant from RGC, and Yigal Gerchak’s research was partially supported by a grant from the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada.

    View full text